Participation criterion

The participation criterion, also called vote or population monotonicity, is a voting system criterion that says that a candidate should never lose an election as a result of receiving too many votes in support.[1][2] More formally, it says that adding more voters who prefer Alice to Bob should not cause Alice to lose the election to Bob.[3]

Voting systems that fail the participation criterion exhibit the no-show paradox,[4] where a voter is effectively disenfranchised by the electoral system because turning out to vote would make the outcome worse. In such a scenario, these voters' ballots are treated as less than worthless, actively harming their own interests by reversing an otherwise-favorable outcome.[5]

The criterion can also be thought of as a weak kind of strategyproofness: while it is impossible for honesty to always be the best strategy (by Gibbard's theorem), the participation criterion guarantees honesty will always "work" as a strategy (i.e. an honest vote will make the outcome better).

Positional methods and score voting satisfy the participation criterion. All methods satisfying paired majority-rule[4][6] can fail in situations involving four-way cyclic ties, though such scenarios are empirically rare. Most notably, instant-runoff voting and the two-round system often fail the participation criterion in competitive elections, typically as a result of center squeeze.[1][2][7]

  1. ^ a b Doron, Gideon; Kronick, Richard (1977). "Single Transferrable Vote: An Example of a Perverse Social Choice Function". American Journal of Political Science. 21 (2): 303–311. doi:10.2307/2110496. ISSN 0092-5853. JSTOR 2110496.
  2. ^ a b Ray, Depankar (1986-04-01). "On the practical possibility of a 'no show paradox' under the single transferable vote". Mathematical Social Sciences. 11 (2): 183–189. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(86)90024-7. ISSN 0165-4896.
  3. ^ Woodall, Douglas (December 1994). "Properties of Preferential Election Rules, Voting matters - Issue 3, December 1994".
  4. ^ a b Moulin, Hervé (1988-06-01). "Condorcet's principle implies the no show paradox". Journal of Economic Theory. 45 (1): 53–64. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(88)90253-0.
  5. ^ Fishburn, Peter C.; Brams, Steven J. (1983-01-01). "Paradoxes of Preferential Voting". Mathematics Magazine. 56 (4): 207–214. doi:10.2307/2689808. JSTOR 2689808.
  6. ^ Brandt, Felix; Geist, Christian; Peters, Dominik (2016-01-01). "Optimal Bounds for the No-Show Paradox via SAT Solving". Proceedings of the 2016 International Conference on Autonomous Agents & Multiagent Systems. AAMAS '16. Richland, SC: International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems: 314–322. arXiv:1602.08063. ISBN 9781450342391.
  7. ^ McCune, David; Wilson, Jennifer (2024-04-07). "The Negative Participation Paradox in Three-Candidate Instant Runoff Elections". arXiv:2403.18857 [physics.soc-ph].

© MMXXIII Rich X Search. We shall prevail. All rights reserved. Rich X Search