Economics of corruption

This article is about the economics of corruption. If you wanted to read about corruption in general, visit article about corruption.

Economics of corruption deals with the misuse of public power for private benefit and its economic impact on society. The goal of the discipline is to study the causes and consequences of corruption and how it affects the economical functioning of the state.

Economies that are afflicted by a high level of corruption are not capable of prospering as fully as those with a low level of corruption. Also, economies that are corrupted are not able to function properly since the natural laws of the economy can not function freely. As a consequence, corruption, for instance, leads to an inefficient allocation of resources, poor education, and healthcare or the presence of a shadow economy - a kind of economy that includes illegal activities as well as unreported income from the production of legal goods and services for which taxes should be paid, but are not.[1][2]

One of the difficulties of studying corruption lies in its definition. This might appear as a minor detail, but how we define corruption affects the way we model it and how we measure it. Although there are many definitions of what corruption is, most of them overlap over the central issue - "the misuse of public office power for personal gain in an illegal manner". Certain illegal activities such as fraud, money laundering, drug trade, and black market operations, do not necessarily amount to corruption if they do not involve the use of public power (bureaucracy).[3][4] Another viable definition is as follows: corruption is an “arrangement” that involves “a private exchange between two parties (the ‘demander’ and the ‘supplier’), which (1) has an influence on the allocation of resources either immediately or in the future, and (2) involves the use or abuse of public or collective responsibility for private ends.”[5]

The pervasiveness of corruption is a probabilistic measure and refers to the likelihood that an entering firm will encounter corruption in its dealings with government officials or politicians in the host country. A high level of pervasiveness indicates that firms are more likely to encounter corruption when undertaking normal business activities.[6]

Research on corruption faces an important empirical obstacle – measurement. Corruption, in its very nature, is illicit and secretive. Large protion of corruption is never discovered or prosecuted.[7] In spite of this burdening issue, researchers have made progress in addressing the level of corruption by attempting to measure the perception of corruption, rather than corruption itself.[4]

As such, one way to objectively measure corruption is by counting the number of criminal indictments for corruption. However, this can be ineffective due to the fact that the ratio of indictments to actual corruption may be highly variable. Often corruption goes unpunished and is thus not counted in this measure. Subjective measures, typically curated via survey data, may be a useful tool to measure corruption. Comparisons between countries may be more comprehensive and consistent, though a fair amount of bias is present in this data as well due to the nature of the subject it measures.

The International Country Risk Guide[8] is a survey of firms on the likelihood they will be asked to make illegal or extralegal payments. The Corruption Perceptions Index[9] is a detailed survey incorporating data from many nations and groups. Finally, the World Bank produces an annual "control of corruption" index that uses similar sources to the International Country Risk Guide and Corruption Perception Index.[10][11]

  1. ^ "How Corruption Affects Emerging Economies". Investopedia. Retrieved 26 April 2024.
  2. ^ ISBN 978-0-521-87275-1, The institutional economics of corruption and reform: Theory, evidence, and policy
  3. ^ Jain, Arvind K. (February 2001). "Corruption: A Review". Journal of Economic Surveys. 15 (1): 71–121. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00133. ISSN 0950-0804.
  4. ^ a b Banerjee, Abhijit; Mullainathan, Sendhil; Hanna, Rema (April 2012). Corruption (Report). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. doi:10.3386/w17968.
  5. ^ Sadig, Ali, The Effects of Corruption on FDI Inflows (June 14, 2009). Cato Journal, Vol. 29, No. 2, 2009, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2264898
  6. ^ Mudambi, Ram; Navarra, Pietro; Delios, Andrew (1 June 2013). "Government regulation, corruption, and FDI". Asia Pacific Journal of Management. 30 (2): 487–511. doi:10.1007/s10490-012-9311-y. ISSN 1572-9958.
  7. ^ "Cost of corruption – GIACC". giaccentre.org. Retrieved 26 April 2024.
  8. ^ "The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG)".
  9. ^ "2018 - Cpi". Archived from the original on 27 April 2019. Retrieved 22 April 2020.
  10. ^ "WGI-Home".
  11. ^ Grimard, Franque. "Corruption". University Lecture. McGill University Leacock Building, Montreal, QC. 2019. Course Content.

© MMXXIII Rich X Search. We shall prevail. All rights reserved. Rich X Search